Instant Runoff and Self-Apportionment (IRSA)
Contents:
Abstract
Overview
Definitions
Procedure
Rationale
Advantages
Disadvantages in perspective
Other design details
Appendix:
Example 1 (12 ballots)
Example 2 (2001 Cambridge school committee)
Abstract:
Common methods for election of a governing body
(council, board or legislature) routinely leave large fractions of constituents
without satisfactory representation, and large imbalances in mandate among
winners. They usually require complex
reapportionment (redistricting) schemes that are easily manipulated by pitting
arbitrary subsets of voters against each other. An
objective method is proposed here that allows voters to naturally reapportion
themselves, leaving nearly everyone with equal and satisfactory
representation.? As a result, a narrow
majority of elected legislators clearly represents a majority of voters, which
is rarely true with the common election methods.
While more complex than a plurality vote, it is less so than current
reapportionment procedures. It
extends concepts of the well-known Instant Runoff and Single Transferable Vote
methods, but it more clearly defines constituencies, is easier to count and
audit, and takes full advantage of the mathematical insights behind them.
Overview:
In this method, voters rank candidates in order of
preference. Votes are counted in a series of
rounds. A vote counts toward one?s highest possible choice, although some candidates may be eliminated,
and elected candidates with too many votes may allow voters to apply a portion
of their vote to lower choices.
Adjustments are made in every round until the number of candidates equals the
number of seats and each has a nearly equal number of votes.
Definitions:
Voton: Each ballot corresponds to one vote, but
each vote can be subdivided into multiples of a fundamental unit, called a
voton. The number of votons in a vote
is equal to the number of seats multiplied by one more than the number of
seats. Votons are the largest units
with an important mathematical property: a winner with too many votes can let
each voter transfer a whole number of votons, and always end up between Enough
and the Ideal Number of votes (which are also whole numbers of votons). If there is only one winner, no such transfers
occur, so votes are not subdivided (one voton per ballot).
Enough votes to win: a number of votons equal to
one more than the product of the total number of ballots (excluding those
counting for "none of these") and the number of seats being elected. If all winners have Enough votes to win, it is
impossible for too many candidates to win.
Ideal Number of votes: a number of votons equal to
the total number of ballots, (excluding those counting for "none of
these") multiplied by one more than the number of seats being elected. If all winners must have more than the Ideal
Number of votes, it is impossible for enough candidates to win. If each winner has exactly the Ideal Number, the
voting power of members of the legislature is exactly proportional to their
number of supportive constituents.
Round: an iteration of steps 1 to 3 of the procedure.
I hope that other terms will be intuitive. The examples below should help clarify how it
works.
Procedure:
0. Voting
Voters rank candidates in order of preference, with
the understanding that if circumstances prevent their vote (or portion thereof)
from counting for a higher choice, it will count for a lower choice.
1. Counting votes
Votons from each ballot are assigned to its
highest-ranked candidate, constrained as follows:
A. Each candidate has a prescribed maximum number of votons per ballot (initially equal to the number in a whole ballot).
B. An elected candidate may only accept a ballot's votons if elected in a later round than any higher-ranked winners.
C. Maxima are waived for votons that cannot otherwise count for a candidate. (They count toward the highest-ranked elected candidate.)
D. A ballot that cannot be counted for a candidate is counted for "none of these".
For each candidate, a record (histogram) is kept of
how many ballots contribute a given number of votons, sorted in decreasing
order of the number of votons per ballot (each pair of numbers is a
"bin"). Ballots that exceed the candidate's maximum and bins
containing zero ballots are not part of the histogram.
2. Adjustment of maxima
A. If any candidate was eliminated in the previous
round, the thresholds (Enough and the Ideal Number) are recomputed.
B. If any candidates have Enough votes to win, they
are declared elected. All
are declared elected if there are exactly enough remaining to fill all seats.
C. Maximum reduction - open seats
This step is invoked if:
i. There are fewer elected candidates than seats, and either
ii. In this round, any candidate could perform this maximum reduction for the first time, or
iii. In the previous round, any candidate was eliminated.
The maximum number of votons that can count for
each elected candidate is reduced as far as possible while ensuring that the
candidate has Enough votes.
Procedure: The maximum is adjusted to the number of
votons per ballot in successive histogram bins, and the number of votons and
ballots above that maximum are each summed until removing those votons would
put the candidate at or below Enough votes. If
below, the maximum is increased by the difference between Enough and the number
of votons that would remain given this adjusted maximum, divided by the number
of ballots summed, rounded up. The maximum is set to zero if transfer of all
votons in the histogram would not put the candidate below Enough.
D. Maximum reduction - filled seats
This step is invoked if:
i. There are no unelected candidates not yet eliminated, and
ii. No candidate with more than the Ideal Number of votes has a maximum of zero.
The maximum number of votons that can count for
each elected candidate is reduced as far as possible while ensuring that the
candidate has at least the Ideal Number of votes.? The procedure follows that of 2.C, substituting "the Ideal
Number" for "Enough".
E. Elimination
This step is invoked if:
i. There are unelected candidates with nonzero maxima, and
ii. No other maximum reduction occurred in this round.
The number of votes for all candidates is sorted
from least to most.? Candidates' votes
are summed in increasing order, omitting from the sum a number of top
candidates equal to the number of seats. The
highest point at which the sum is less than the votes for the next candidate is
identified. Candidates below that point are
eliminated, and the maxima for those candidates are set to zero.
If the candidates with the fewest nonzero votes are
tied and the tie must be resolved to choose a candidate to eliminate, a
candidate is chosen randomly.
3. Repeat steps 1 through 3 until no further
changes can be made.
Mid-term vacancies due to resignations or
disqualifications can be refilled by recounting the election, considering only
the unelected candidates, and using only the ballots counting toward the
vacated seats along with the "none of these" ballots.
If a few ballots are to be added or removed, this can often be done without a full recount.? In each round, the ballots are added or subtracted from the tally.? The Enough and Ideal thresholds are corrected by Seats or Seats+1 votons for each counted ballot.? The new totals are checked to see if there are changes to who is newly elected in the round, and to see if the gap in the elimination sum has changed, if applicable.? For each elected candidate, the remainders in maximum calculations are corrected for the threshold change, and by the number of ballots added or removed from the affected bins, in addition to the votons contributed by those ballots.? If there are no changes to who is elected or eliminated and no changes in maxima in any round, a full recount is not necessary.
If the election is counted without the assistance of a computer, it would be merciful to cause 2.D to terminate after a round with no new candidate able to reduce.?
Rationale behind this method:
?
This voting method uses lists of preferences made
by voters from among a meaningful variety of viable candidates to elect a
board, council, or legislative body in which:
- all members have a nearly equal mandate
- nearly all voters have satisfactory representation
- a clear and traceable definition of constituencies exists to connect voters to representatives
- a majority of the legislative body traceably represents the consent of a majority of voters.
This is achieved without the need for a separate
redistricting process, or at least a less complicated one that divides a large
legislature into geographic groups of roughly 5-10 seats. It is a variation of the "single transferable
vote" methods, drawing from the Meek and Gregory versions.
STV has been around for more than 100 years, so why
do we need another variation?
Because it is still not used as widely as many of us think it should. A main reason for this is that it is difficult to
implement and understand, and the advantages are not always clear to people. Improvements to the method that build on past
successes and failures can reduce the magnitude of these obstacles.
IRSA has the following advantages over older Single
Transferable Vote methods:
1. It is reasonably easy to hand count and audit,
using whole numbers of discrete votons.
There are no worries about floating point errors or rounding precision.? The reliance of the Meek method on taking
many infinitesimal slices off each ballot is absent.
2. It is simple and deterministic: who one's vote
counts for can be determined at any point knowing only one's rankings, the
maximum number of votons per ballot countable toward a candidate, and the order
in which candidates have been elected. You
do not need to know who the ballot counted for previously. Randomness is used only to break ties, and this is
usually unnecessary.? Independence on
detailed ballot history greatly simplifies audits.
3. With most other versions, if a single vote needs
to be added or removed from the count, or if a mistake was made in an early
round, it is necessary to recount the entire election in order to have an exact
result. With IRSA, this is rarely the
case, because surplus transfers only occur when everyone in a histogram bin can
contribute one voton.
4. It scales well down to a small number of votes,
making the method usable by small organizations or communities. A single vote with a sufficient number of rankings
can produce a meaningful outcome.
Many methods sacrifice this feature by using thresholds rounded to the nearest
ballot, a facade for the complexity of floating-point ballot fractions.? When there are few votes, this causes the
Enough threshold to exceed the Ideal threshold, causing strange results.? Discrete votons allow whole-number
thresholds but avoid this problem.
5. It approaches the ideal outcome: each winner has
about (100/seats)% of the vote, except for a small pile of ballots that rank no
winners. This is in contrast to the Meek
method, which is very good at giving winners a mandate that looks equal, but
which does so by converging on the wrong threshold, shoveling huge numbers of
perfectly good votes into the garbage can in the process.
6. It captures or closely approximates desirable
properties of traditional STV methods.
Voters in a constituency with enough votes for two seats can all rank the same
favorite and second favorite and elect both.
Surplus transfers are fair and deterministic, and strategic voting is not
worthwhile in practice.
7. It shows moderation and equity in the slicing up
of ballots, helping to provide a clear connection between voters and their
representatives. Nearly everyone ends up with one
or two representatives, both receiving a large fraction of their vote. In the process, it does a good job of honoring
higher rankings.
8. It is Pareto optimal: ballots ranked AB and BA
do not each end up giving votons to both A and B, making them wish they could
trade votons.? Traditional STV methods
have not paid attention to this, but it is a valuable feature in an
apportionment method.
9. It provides a clear measure of unsatisfied voters.? Only ballots that do not rank any winning candidates appear in the "None of these" pile.
Disadvantages in perspective:
1. With discrete votons, surplus transfers are not
always complete, but they are very close to that in practical cases. With fully ranked ballots, the worst-case surplus
transfer error is (% of vote for winner)/(seats*(seats+1)) - always leaving the
winner between Enough and the Ideal Number.
Recycling of exhausted ballots also reveals a type of incomplete transfer that
is present but masked in most methods that do not recycle. Here, most elected candidates have more than one
chance to transfer a surplus, greatly improving completeness.
The use of discrete votons is a much more benign
simplification than limiting the number of rankings that voters can list, which
causes many ballots to be involuntarily exhausted. Regardless, the latter seems to be a tradeoff
between functionality and simplicity of implementation (SF bay area, London)
that has been crucial to making ranked ballot methods politically viable.? This may sound like a straw-man argument,
but it is important to be grounded by practicality. If simplicity is of paramount concern, discrete
votons are a good step toward that.
2. Fault can be found with any solution to the
Solomonic problem of dividing a winner's ballots into some that transfer and
some that do not. Most other approaches either
involve either randomness or more ballot slicing. In
others, most of the ballots can be left unsliced, at the expense of a small
number that become sliced finely. The
use of maxima gives transfer priority to previously unsliced ballots. This way, every ballot has an equal opportunity to
be sliced, but is unlikely to be sliced more than once. Such equal treatment removes opportunities for
strategic voting. Limiting repeated slices more clearly establishes one or two
specific winning candidates as one's representative, and makes it easy to audit
the election and determine who one's vote counted for.
3. Rule 1B (transfer only to later winners) makes
counting each ballot more difficult, and in other versions is criticized for
allowing a type of strategic voting in which one votes for an obvious
first-round winner and then surfs along the surpluses of several other
candidates, helping several of them win.
This does not occur here, because surplus votons usually have low priority for
subsequent transfers, and they end up in the same place as they would if the
strategy were not used.
Voting for the obvious winner does not guarantee that one can transfer more
votons, because maxima are also affected by the number of recycled ballots. In other methods, voting for an obvious loser can
also allow surplus surfing, but with this method, these ballots are
indistinguishable from those that don't attempt the strategy after the loser is
eliminated.
Usually, without a rule like 1B, if all of winner
A's second choices are winner B, and all of B's second choices are A, everyone
will end up with their second choices, and each ballot must be recounted many
times. The Meek method mitigates this
by bleeding ballots into the exhausted pile or to lower choices. If that approach is not acceptable, it is hard to
avoid 1B.
If we are using our counting method to achieve
apportionment, we care about Pareto optimality.
This means that we do not want to have situations where ballots ranked AB and
BA each end up giving votons to both A and B. We
do not want to leave voters wishing they could trade votons so that they have
more votons counting toward their first choice.
Meek, which essentially always gives weight to lower-ranked winners, is
normally suboptimal. By
allowing transfers from winners only to those elected later, suboptimality can
be avoided.
4. In general, the rule set is not as simple as
possible, but it is simpler than most other proposals. Some rules make actual counting easier, create a
clearer connection between winners and constituents (fewer repeatedly sliced
ballots), and allow a clearer measure of unsatisfied voters.
5. This method does not smoothly accommodate
ballots with equal rankings.
Some other approaches do by splitting votes equally among equal-ranked
candidates, constrained by surpluses and eliminations. When using discrete votons, such splitting can
leave a remainder that counts for no one, but must be kept track of, because
the leftover votons may be countable later.
Also, if a ballot counts recycled votons toward a candidate (due to 1C), the
ballot must not change when the candidate?s
maximum changes, and this doesn?t
work if those votons are split among multiple candidates. There are ways to count equal rankings, such as
dividing them equally without regard to maxima, but they do not fit seamlessly
with these rules. Liberal use of slicing to
process equal rankings is contrary to this method?s
goal of creating a clearly defined relationship between a voter and a small
number of representatives.
Other design details:
Number of actions per round ? If transfers from winners and losers are handled one at a time instead
of allowing several simultaneous transfers, a method can slightly improve the
efficacy of surplus transfers in electing their next choices, and of
convergence on the Ideal Number of votes.
However, the benefit is tiny, and the paperwork is more complicated, making
hand counts tedious and results more verbose.
Ties also occur more frequently.
Where to recycle ballots - when votons cannot count
toward lower choices, it is perhaps more intuitive to leave votons with the
low-ranked winning candidate for whom they most recently counted. However, giving votons to their highest-ranked
winner is respectful of the voter's preferences.
Furthermore, a major function of recycled votons is to help candidates achieve
the ideal number of votes. It
is difficult for candidates elected near the end of the count to get rid of
ballots above the ideal number. If
ballots can recycle to highest-ranked winners, the votons have a place to go.
If the term "voton" invokes daunting
thoughts of nuclear physics, a plainer term such as "pieces" could be
used.
The major features that distinguish IRSA from earlier STV versions enable each other, or provide added benefits by their combination. Votons enable exact thresholds and histogram-based surplus transfers that minimize repeated slicing and simplify incremental ballot additions.? Recycling of exhausted pieces enables convergence on the Ideal Number, and is also necessary for exact thresholds and Pareto optimality.? Allowing transfers only to later winners enables Pareto optimality as well as independence of a ballot on its specific history, while also enabling convergence on the Ideal Number.? Half-baked versions of IRSA are conceivable, but they would have less than half the benefits.
Most election reformers are ironically conservative
about the methods they support.
This is actually sensible, given the plethora of ideas and approaches out
there. The fact remains, though, that
STV does not have the balance between performance and complexity to get across
the "valley of death" that technologies must bridge to get from a few
specialty uses to widespread adoption, and significant conceptual changes are
needed to achieve this. I
believe that the approach proposed here offers major improvements to both
performance and simplicity of implementation that will allow obstacles to
adoption to be overcome.
Appendix: Two example counts (many more are available at demochoice.org)
Example 1
This artificial example demonstrates most of the
major features of the method. It
should be possible to follow along by counting the ballots yourself as the
maxima change.
Candidates: 6 (A through F)
Seats: 3
Votons per ballot: 12
Ballots: 12
Votons: 144
Ballots:
A B
A B
A C
A D
A E
B
B
C B
C D
D B
E
F C A
Initial maximum for each candidate is 12.
Enough votes to win = 144/4 + 1 = 37
Ideal number of votes = 144/3 = 48
Round 1 count:
A B C D E F
60 24 24 12 12 12
Ballots count as (listing number of votons immediately after candidate; no number = no votons):
A12 B
A12 B
A12 C
A12 D
A12 E
B12
B12
C12 B
C12 D
D12 B
E12
F12 C A
A has Enough votes and is elected.
A's histogram is 12: 5 (5 ballots that count 12 votons for A)
A's maximum can be adjusted to 8 by inspection (8*5=40 votons; 7*5=35 which is below Enough, so 8 is as low as possible). The maximum reduction procedure defined in the rules works for more complicated histograms, and is shown below.
Round 2 count:
Ballots in A's histogram are recounted, using the reduced maximum for A.
A B C D E F
40 32 28 16 16 12
Ballots count as:
A8 B4
A8 B4
A8 C4
A8 D4
A8 E4
B12
B12
C12 B
C12 D
D12 B
E12
F12 C A
A's histogram is now 8: 5.
A's maximum cannot be adjusted further.
F is eliminated.
Round 3 count:
A B C D E F
40 32 40 16 16 --
Ballots count as:
A8 B4
A8 B4
A8 C4
A8 D4
A8 E4
B12
B12
C12 B
C12 D
D12 B
E12
F C12 A
C has Enough votes and is elected.
C's histogram is 12: 3, 4: 1.
C's maximum can be adjusted to 11, leaving C with Enough votes.
To go through the detailed procedure to determine
the maximum:
The maximum is set to the number of votons in the first bin (12). This would not reduce the number of votons counting for C.
The maximum is set to the number of votons in the second bin (4). This would leave C with 16 votons. This is 21 votons fewer than Enough votes. There are 3 ballots in higher bins, and we need each to make up the difference, so the maximum must be 4+21/3 = 11.
Round 4 count:
A B C D E F
40 33 38 17 16 --
Ballots count as:
A8 B4
A8 B4
A8 C4
A8 D4
A8 E4
B12
B12
C11 B1
C11 D1
D12 B
E12
F C12 A
A voton from ballot F C A was returned to C. It cannot be counted for A due to rule 1B.
No further maximum adjustments are possible. E is eliminated.
Suppose that E had 17 votes. In this case, E would be tied with D. Their histograms are hypothetically:
D 12: 1, 4: 1, 1: 1
E 12: 1, 5: 1
The tie-breaking procedure would resolve this by dropping the smallest bin, leaving D with fewer votes than E, and D would be eliminated instead.
Round 5 count:
A B C D E F None
44 33 38 17 -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A8 B4
A8 B4
A8 C4
A8 D4
A12 E
B12
B12
C11 B1
C11 D1
D12 B
E
F C12 A
One ballot went to None of these, so the thresholds must be recomputed:
Enough = 132/4 + 1 = 34
Ideal = 132/3 = 44
A's histogram is 8: 4 (a ballot that exceeded the maximum was removed).
A's maximum is reduced to 6.
C's histogram is 11: 2, 4: 1 (a ballot that exceeded the maximum was removed).
C's maximum is reduced to 9.
Round 6 count:
A B C D E F None
36 39 36 21 -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A6 B6
A6 B6
A6 C6
A6 D6
A12 E
B12
B12
C9 B3
C9 D3
D12 B
E
F C12 A
B has Enough votes and is elected.
All seats are filled, so D is eliminated.
Round 7 count:
A B C D E F None
42 51 39 -- -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A6 B6
A6 B6
A6 C6
A12 D
A12 E
B12
B12
C9 B3
C12 D
D B12
E
F C12 A
B has more than the Ideal.
B's histogram is 12: 3, 6: 2, 3: 1. To shed 6 votons, the maximum is reduced to 10.
Round 8 count:
A B C D E F None
42 51 39 -- -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A6 B6
A6 B6
A6 C6
A12 D
A12 E
B12
B12
C9 B3
C12 D
D B12
E
F C12 A
This didn't work; B can only shed votons by recycling to higher winners.
A second try is allowed.
B's histogram is 6: 2, 3: 1. The maximum is reduced to 3.
Round 9 count:
A B C D E F None
48 45 39 -- -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A9 B3
A9 B3
A6 C6
A12 D
A12 E
B12
B12
C9 B3
C12 D
D B12
E
F C12 A
A now has more than the Ideal.
Histogram: 6: 1; new maximum is 2.
B is 3: 3; no change is possible.
Round 10 count:
A B C D E F None
45 45 42 -- -- -- 12
Ballots count as:
A9 B3
A9 B3
A3 C9
A12 D
A12 E
B12
B12
C9 B3
C12 D
D B12
E
F C12 A
No further changes are allowed. Final maxima are 2, 3, 9, 0, 0, 0.
Example 2
A version of the Cambridge, MA 2001 school
committee election was counted using these rules on a spreadsheet. For convenience, I used a sample of 20% of the
ballots. There are 11 candidates for 6
seats. Tallies are in terms of votons. Note that recounts between rounds require
consultation of only those ballots from histogram bins that are above newly
changed maxima.
Candidates: 11
Seats: 6
Votons per ballot: 42
Ballots: 3298
Votons: 138516
Round 1
w/i Baker Delan Erlien Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser
378 2352 1806 10458 23268 18396 13986 16296 12684 24024 14868
Enough: 19789
Ideal: 23086 (these numbers change only after an elimination)
Fantini and Turkel are newly elected.
Surpluses, histograms, and new maxima of elected candidates:
Fantini (3479) 42: 554. Max = 36
Turkel (4235) 42: 572. Max = 35
Surpluses are in parentheses.
In histograms, the number before a colon is a number of votons on a ballot counting toward candidate. Following the colon is the number of ballots counting that many votons.
Maxima are 42 at the beginning of the count, and only changed maxima are noted; these apply to the next round.
Round 2
w/i Baker Delan Erlien Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser
384 2539 1962 10814 20556 20418 14315 16704 14113 20594 16117
Grassi is newly elected.
Fantini (767) 36: 452. Max = 35
Grassi (629) 42: 438, 6: 331. Max = 41
Turkel (805) 36: 490. Max = 34
Round 3
w/i Baker Delan Erlien Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser
386 2595 2018 10879 20104 20499 14429 16782 14387 20104 16333
write-in, Baker, and Delaney are eliminated (their maxima become zero).
Round 4
Erlien Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser None
11227 21511 21229 14741 17199 14543 20228 16704 1134
Enough: 19627
Ideal: 22897
Fantini (1884) 35: 467. Max = 31
Grassi (1602) 41: 224, 8: 40, 7: 325. Max = 34
Turkel (601) 34: 485. Max = 33
Round 5
Erlien Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser None
11457 19643 21001 15412 17494 15403 19743 17229 1134
Erlien is eliminated (max = 0).
Round 6
Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser None
19970 21365 17857 19504 17458 22038 18560 1764
Enough: 19537
Ideal: 22792
Fantini (433) 31: 464.
Grassi (1828) 34: 218, 11: 330, 9: 41. Max = 26
Turkel (2501) 33: 538. Max = 29
Round 7
Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser None
19970 19785 18605 20000 18814 19886 19692 1764
Price and Walser are newly elected.
Fantini (433) 31: 464.
Grassi (248) 26: 218, 13: 41, 11: 330. Max = 25
Price (463) 42: 440, 16: 29, 13: 66, 11: 18. Max = 41
Turkel (349) 29: 538. Max = 29
Walser (155) 42: 386, 16: 43, 13: 197, 11: 21.
Round 8
Fantini Grassi Hardin Price Segat Turkel Walser None
19970 19567 18829 19706 19059 19886 19735 1764
Harding is eliminated (max = 0).
Round 9
Fantini Grassi Price Segat Turkel Walser None
21339 22674 24093 21757 21677 21264 5712
Enough: 18973
Ideal: 22134
Segat is newly elected; all seats are filled.
Grassi and Price approach Ideal for the first time.
Grassi (540) 25: 200, 13: 51, 11: 359. Max = 23
Price (1959) 41: 284, 17: 52, 13: 81, 11: 24. Max = 35
Round 10
Fantini Grassi Price Segat Turkel Walser None
21339 22274 22493 23651 21677 21370 5712
Segat approaches Ideal for the first time.
Grassi (140) 23: 200, 13: 51, 11: 359.
Price (359) 35: 284, 19: 52, 13: 81, 11: 24. Max = 34
Segat (1517) 42: 388, 19: 95, 13: 219, 11: 65, 7: 284. Max = 39
Round 11
Fantini Grassi Price Segat Turkel Walser None
21339 22274 22209 23935 21677 21370 5712
Grassi (140) 23: 200, 13: 51, 11: 359.
Price (75) 34: 284, 19: 52, 13: 81, 11: 24.
Segat (1801) 19: 95, 13: 219, 11: 65, 8: 284. Max = 10
Round 12
Fantini Grassi Price Segat Turkel Walser None
21404 23129 22209 22358 22334 21370 5712
Turkel is above Ideal for the first time, but can't reduce maximum.
Grassi (995) 23: 105, 13: 51, 11: 359. Max = 14
Price (75) 34: 284, 19: 52, 13: 81, 11: 24.
Segat (1801) 10: 379, 8: 284.
Turkel (200) 29: 346.
The standard deviation from the Ideal Number of
votes is 664 votons (15.8 ballots).
This is 3% of the Ideal Number, 0.5% of the total, and about 28% of the
difference between Enough and the Ideal Number.
Slicing: At the end, 1636 ballots counted toward a
single candidate, 1526 counted toward two, and 136 ballots did not rank a
winner.
Depth is the percentage of votons counting toward a
certain position among the rankings.
Cumulative depth is the percentage counting toward that ranking or higher.
Depth
Cumulative
1st 71.6 71.6
2nd 19.6 91.3
3rd 6.0 97.3
4th 1.7 98.9
5th 0.7 99.7
6th 0.2 99.9
7th 0.1 100
8th 0.0 100